To be published (in Dutch) in Beleid en Maatschapij, symposium on “Nog steeds een mirakel? De legitimiteit van het poldermodel in de eenentwintigste eeuw“, ed by Maarten Keune, Amsterdam University Press
The totemic status of the Dutch polder model may have waned somewhat since the publication of Visser and Hemerijck’s “Dutch Miracle” in 1997, but in comparative terms Dutch neo-corporatism – the system whereby trade unions and employers get to decisively shape social and economic policies – still displays a remarkable degree of stability compared with other European countries. Ireland, for instance, another country considered a neo-corporatist miracle in the 1990s and 2000s, has witnessed the virtual collapse of its social partnership model in the aftermath of the financial crisis (Culpepper and Regan, 2014). While neocorporatism seemed to have undergone a revival in Southern Europe in the 1990s (Hancke & Rhodes 2005), the crisis and the need to cut back spending have led to the marginalisation of employers and trade unions there as well, with the possible exception of Portugal. Austrian corporatism, probably one of the most developed in the world, has seen its legitimacy undermined by populist challengers (the FPö, the Austrian counterpart of the PVV), and scandals involving banks controlled by the trade unions (Afonso, 2013). While Switzerland has also performed well in the aftermath of the crisis, the role of social partners there has also been challenged by party polarisation and the strengthening of populist parties (Haeusermann et al 2004; Afonso & Papadopoulos 2015).
In contrast, while the Dutch economy has also faced serious consequences as a result of the financial crisis, notably a high level of household debt, and its political system has faced a similar populist upsurge coming from Geert Wilders’s Freedom party, the Dutch Polder model seems to display a good level of resilience in the face of these challenges. Hence, the volume edited by Maarten Keune draws a nuanced picture of the Poldermodel, looking at its economic performance and political legitimacy. Drawing on the contributions of the book, I will address a series of challenges the Dutch border and more all is faced, mainly from our comparative perspective, and seek to answer why it seems to have survived, and the whether it could be exported. I will first draw in assessments of the current state of the Polder model based on the contributions of the book, then address the following challenges: political change and the challenge of populist parties, changes in the economic structure at the level of finance and labour markets, and finally address the potential for the diffusion of the Polder model to other countries in the context of the Eurozone crisis.
Performance
As made clear in the chapter by Caelesta Braun, as well as Maarten Keune’s introductory chapter, the legitimacy and resilience of neocorporatism rested on its ability to deliver better economic performance – output legitimacy – which would outweigh its inconvenient in terms of input legitimacy, or its ability to aggregate the preferences of a majority of voters. In the words of Norwegian political scientist Stein Rokkan (1966), in neocorporatism, “votes count, but resources decide”. The Dutch Polder model matched to this idea: social pacts negotiated between trade unions, employers and the government have shaped a number of important reforms in social protection, labour market regulation and wage setting while parliament often merely rubber-stamped agreements. From the point of view of input legitimacy, this is problematic given that only one in six Dutch workers is a member of a trade union.
But is this democratic deficit justified by superior economic performance? As shown by Visser in his contribution, the Dutch economy has been performing well over the last decades in terms of both employment and equality. While employment levels have been among the highest in Europe, especially among women and young people, the Dutch labour market has been astonishingly spared by the rise in inequalities that has spanned all advanced economies since the 1980s. This pattern can be accounted for by the persisting high coverage of collective labour agreements in spite of the dwindling membership of trade unions (outlined in the contribution by Paul de Beer), and the expansion of employment underpinned by the creation of a large number of – mostly part-time – jobs. Hence, the Dutch model is a good example of the “high employment road to low inequality” presented by Kenworthy (2009; Afonso & Visser 2015). Arguably, as Keune makes clear, the Dutch economy has been an outstanding jobs-creation machine, but not a work-creation machine if one considers the huge proportion of part-time jobs in the economy and the total number of working hours performed. Yet, work-sharing via the wide distribution of part-time work – as compared to the concentrated participation on (male) full-time workers that prevails in Southern Europe, for example – is arguably a good solution to achieve low inequality in a political context which doesn’t allow for mass public sector expansion, as in Scandinavian countries. Hence, one possible reason for the survival and resilience of the Polder model is that it has made it possible to deliver both economic performance and provided an effective shield against inequality.
The main output-related argument in favour of the Polder model has been that a particular type of political process involving cooperation between unions and employers has been the cause of the good economic performance of the Dutch economy. The main transmission channel connecting them has been wage restraint: by containing wage increases, the Polder Model has allegedly made it possible to preserve the competitive position of the largely export-oriented Dutch economy, and deliver better employment outcomes. However, this causal relationship can be questioned in a number of respects. One of the most severe criticisms is the one expressed by Ewald Engelen. Rather than an export-driven success, Dutch economic performance has been the result of a hybrid system where the domestic consequences of wage restraint have been compensated by a form of “private keynesianism” propelled mostly by mortgage debt. Hence, high employment happened could have happened despite, rather than because of the Polder Model of wage compression. While wage restraint has dampened domestic demand, mortgage debt has been used to boost it, notably policies such as the Hypotheekrenteaftrek. Hence, the high level of household debt in the Netherlands – Dutch households were the most indebted in the euro area in 2015, with debt representing 283% of household income – may actually be a flipside of the Polder model. This high level of indebtedness is often presented as a major reason for the slow recovery of the Dutch economy after the crisis in comparison with, say, Belgium (FT Alphaville 2016). After the fall of house prices, Dutch households have sought to balance their books and hoarded consumption.
Populism and Electoral Fragmentation
The first challenge faced by the Dutch Polder Model is the increasing fragmentation of the Dutch party system, the weakening of the traditional advocates of corporatist compromises in the legislative arena, and the rise of a populist party claiming to represent the traditional base of trade unions. As emphasised by Keune in his contribution, strong corporatism needs a strong government. This has been especially important when it comes to the regulation of the labour markets via CAOs (explained in the contribution by Verhoeff). In the face of declining trade union membership, political intervention has been a pillar of corporatist compromises by systematically extending collective bargaining outcomes and making them compulsory. Traditionally, the parties that have defended corporatist compromises in the Dutch context have been the PvdA and to some extent the CDA. Now, these parties have faced a dramatic electoral decline over the last decades. In 1993, the CDA and the PvdA represented 66% of parliamentary seats in the Tweede Kamer. After the 2012 elections, this share had fallen to 33%, and projections for the 2017 elections at the time of writing gave 8% and 10% for the PvDA and the CDA respectively. Hence, the channels of transmission of the Polder model into politics have become fairly thin.
The new parties that have emerged or been strengthened in recent years have adopted a generally more critical stance towards neo-corporatist institutions, and had less problems with sidelining trade unions and employers. The “Lenteakkoord” concluded in 2012 between the VVD, CDA, D66, ChristenUnie and GroenLinks was an example of this. One reason is that the extreme proportionality of the Dutch electoral system has facilitated the autonomisation of new middle class constituencies and their move away from the fore of social democracy to new parties (D66, Groenlinks; 50+ and others) with somewhat different socio-economic positions, and the weakening of their organic ties with trade unions. In other countries where the electoral system makes it more difficult for new parties to emerge, these constituencies are kept together, usually under the umbrella of a social-democratic party.
The counterpart of the shrinking of the pro-Polder parties in parliament has been the rise of the PVV as a powerful opposition force with a resolute anti-Polder position. In his Onafhangelijkeidverklaring from 2005, Wilders wrote that the Poldermodel “moet op de helling, zonder pardon, en dat betekent dus het einde van de praat- en overlegpaleizen als de SER en de Stichting van de Arbeid”, as well as “Het afschaffen van het algemeen verbindend verklaren van CAO’s” (PVV 2005). As other populist parties in Europe, the PVV has been very critical of neo-corporatist institutions perceived to work like a political cartel from which it is mostly excluded. Dismantling it is a way to undermine the cosy relationship between mainstream parties and interest groups, and especially trade unions. Interestingly, trade unions typically represented the socio-economic clienteles that the PVV is now mostly claiming, namely older, low-and-middle skilled working class workers. Weakening their influence can also be part of a strategy to become the only voice of this constituency. In 2011, for instance, the PVV proposed to give voting rights to non-union members in the negotiations of collective labour agreements as a way to dilute the influence of labour organisations (BNR 2011)
This being said, the increasing fragmentation of the party system may not necessarily mean the end of the Polder model. Indeed, as examples in other countries show, the polarisation of politics may actually constitute an opportunity for social partners because of their continuing ability to reach compromises when political parties can’t (Afonso 2013). Hence, in the perspective of a multi-party government in which agreements may be difficult to reach, readymade solutions by social partners may still be able to make their way into policy.
Political-Economic Change
The last important challenge for the Poldermodel is the change in the economic structure. This mainly relates to the evolution of the labour market and its attainment of a potential ceiling and the increasing financialisation of the Dutch economy, especially when it comes to the pension system (explained in the contribution by Van der Zwan).
The first challenge has to do with the ability of the Polder model to deliver superior economic performance, especially when it comes to women. In many respects the “jobs miracle” that took place in the Netherlands in the 1980s and 1990s was based on the creation of part-time jobs mainly taken up by women. This expansion was fairly spectacular, but it was mainly a catching-up phenomenon in comparative terms because female employment in the Netherlands started at very low levels. In fact, The Netherlands had the lowest level of female labour force participation in Europe 1971, nearly 20% below the OECD average. The publication of the Dutch Miracle in 1997 corresponded to this level just about reaching the OECD average. Since then, the potential for increasing female labour force participation has shrunk, and the rate of increase between 1996-2015 and 1985-1995 has halved. Now it is unclear which potential source of labour can be used to increase the labour force. If the output legitimacy of the Polder Model was based on mass job creation, it may now be running out of steam.
The second aspect relates to the increasing financialisation of the Dutch economy, the in-built volatility this introduces, and how it changes the preferences of the actors involved. First, the compromises that underpinned the Polder Model were premised on the ability of domestic actors to exert some control over economic parameters via economic policy choices. Second, it was based on a class compromise between actors with clear interests, namely employers wanting wage restraint and trade unions wanting jobs, better purchasing power and/or social protection. As outlined in van der Zwan and Engelen’s contributions, these assumptions have been severely challenge by the tremendous increase in the level of financialisation of the Dutch economy. In 1995, stocks traded represented 25% of Dutch GDP. By 2000, they represented 150%, and 183% in 2007, with very high levels of volatility, notably after the Dot.com bubble and the global financial crisis. This factor has challenged some basic tenets of the Polder model in two major ways. First, the heavy level of involvement of pension funds jointly managed by social partners in financial markets has blurred the interests of capital and labour. The future income of workers via pension benefits is tied to investment decisions which may go against the interests of other workers, for instance by favouring short-term profits over long-term investments. In a nutshell, workers have become capitalists by procuration. Secondly, and most importantly the high level of volatility and uncertainty brought in by financialisation has made corporatist compromises extremely vulnerable to events happening in financial markets, which are globalised. Hence, it has become more difficult for corporatist actors to make credible commitments – eg. about pension benefits – since revenues are largely beyond their direct control, and may undergo high levels of volatility.
In sum, while the Polder model has indeed displayed a fairly high degree of resilience, it hasn’t been immune to broader political and economic developments which could possibly fundamentally transform it in the long term. While it is unlikely to disappear, it may however be deprived of much of its regulatory capacity in a context of financialisation, and the economic “Miracle” which attracted wide international attention is going to be difficult to sustain, let alone renew. Keune’s edited volume convincingly recognises its successes, but also convincingly highlights its many hidden vectors of instability.
Bibliography
Afonso, Alexandre, and Yannis Papadopoulos. 2015. “How the Populist Radical Right Transformed Swiss Welfare Politics: From Compromises to Polarization.” Swiss Political Science Review 21(4): 617–35.
Afonso, Alexandre. 2013. Social Concertation in Times of Austerity. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
BNR. 2011. Jacht op vakbonden is geopend.
Culpepper, P. D., and A. Regan. 2014. “Why Don’t Governments Need Trade Unions Anymore? The Death of Social Pacts in Ireland and Italy.” Socio-Economic Review 12(4): 723–45.
Afonso, A and Visser, J. 2014. “The Liberal Corporatist Road to High Employment and Low Inequality? The Dutch and Swiss Social Models in the Crisis, in Dølvik, Jon Erik, and Andrew Martin. 2015. European Social Models from Crisis to Crisis: Employment and Inequality in the Era of Monetary Integration. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Financial Times. 2016. Why is the Netherlands doing so badly? https://ftalphaville.ft.com/2016/06/16/2166258/why-is-the-netherlands-doing-so-badly/ (January 4, 2017).
Hancke, B. and Rhodes, M. 2005. “EMU and Labor Market Institutions in Europe: The Rise and Fall of National Social Pacts.” Work and Occupations 32(2): 196–228.
Häusermann, Silja, André Mach, and Yannis Papadopoulos. 2004. “From Corporatism to Partisan Politics: Social Policy Making under Strain in Switzerland.” Swiss Political Science Review 10(2): 33–59.
Kenworthy, Lane. 2009. “The High-Employment Route to Low Inequality.” Challenge 52(5): 77–99.
Rokkan, S. 1966. “Norway: Numerical Democracy and Corporate Pluralism.” In Political Oppositions in Western Democracies, ed. R. A. Dahl. Yale: Yale University Press.
Partij voor de Vrijheid. 2005 “Onafhangelijkheidsvreklaring” http://www.pvv.nl/index.php/component/content/article/30-publicaties/684-onafhankelijkheidsverklaring (January 4, 2017).